Skip to content
Licensed Unlicensed Requires Authentication Published by De Gruyter September 13, 2017

Competitive Search with Ex-post Opportunism

  • Pedro Gomis-Porqueras , Benoît Julien and Liang Wang EMAIL logo

Abstract:

We consider a frictional market where an element of the terms of trade (price or quantity) is posted ex-ante (before the matching process) while the other is determined ex-post. By doing so, sellers can exploit their local monopoly power by adjusting prices or quantities once the local demand is realized. We find that when sellers can adjust quantities ex-post, there exists a unique symmetric equilibrium where an increase in the buyer-seller ratio leads to higher quantities and prices. When buyers instead can choose quantities ex-post, a higher buyer-seller ratio leads to higher prices but lower traded quantities. These equilibrium allocations are generically constrained inefficient in both intensive and extensive margins. When sellers post ex-ante quantities and adjust prices ex-post, a symmetric equilibrium exists where buyers obtain no surplus from trade. This equilibrium allocation is not constrained efficient either. If buyers choose prices ex-post, there is no trade in equilibrium when entry is costly.

JEL Classification: D40; L10

Funding statement: Australian Research Council, (Grant / Award Number: ’DP1701014229’)

Appendix

A Proof of Lemma 1

Define q¯ such that u(q¯)=q¯c(q¯), i.e., B(q¯)=0, and p¯=c(q¯). We summarize the seller’s optimal ex-post choice as follows:

p={c(q~)forp(0,p¯),u(q~)/q~forp(p¯,).

It is important to highlight that both of these solutions imply a monotone relationship between quantity and price. Notice the following

pp¯q~(p)=1/c(q~)>0 (not binding),p>p¯q~(p)=q~2q~u(q~)u(q~)<0 (binding).

In a competitive search equilibrium with Θ(0,) , the positive measure of deviating sellers can choose a price that is either in (0,p¯] and the constraint is not binding, or in (p¯,) under a binding constraint. Define the first possible deviation as p1=c(q~1) and the second possible deviation as p2=u(q~2)/q~2. It is easy to show that the sellers’ expected payoffs are

π1α(Θ)[q~1c(q~1)c(q~1)] and π2α(Θ)[q~2u(q~2)/q~2c(q~2)],

while for buyers we have

U1α(Θ)Θ[u(q~1)q~1c(q~1)]>0=α(Θ)Θ[u(q~2)q~2u(q~2)/q~2]U2.

It is clear that B~(p2)=0 holds when the buyer’s surplus is fully extracted. Thus no buyers would participate in a deviating submarket that offers p2 and q~2. Buyers fully anticipate that the sellers’ best ex-post choice is to fully extract all of their surplus. As a result, it must be the case that the competitive search equilibrium price is p(0,p¯]. The optimal ex-post choice is then p1=c(q~1)(0,p¯]. In other words, buyers anticipate that q~1(p1) is the equilibrium sellers’ response.

B Proof of Proposition 1

To show existence, first, rewrite eq. (8) as

(16)ε(Θ)=B(q)S(q)B(q)S(q)B(q)S(q)χ(q).

This condition characterizes q(Θ). According to Lemma 1, p=c(q). Since B(q)=u(q)c(q)q , we find B(0)=0=S(0). Then, !q¯>0 such that B(q¯)=0. In addition, !q_(0,q¯) such that B(q_)=0. For q(q_,q¯),

B(q)=u(q)c(q)c(q)q<0,B(q)=u(q)2c(q)c(q)q<0 if c(q)0 or c(q)<0 not too negative.

Thus, under these sufficient conditions, we have that B(q) is downward concave. Similarly, we find that for S(q)=c(q)qc(q) ,

S(q)=c(q)q>0,S(q)=c(q)+c(q)q>0 if c(q)0 or c(q)<0 not too negative.

Hence, under these sufficient conditions we have that S(q) is upward convex. We also have that χ(q_)=1 andχ(q¯)=0, with χ(q)>0, q[q_,q¯). Since we focus on matching technologies with constant returns to scale, it follows that ε(Θ)(0,1), Θ(0,). Therefore, given ε(Θ), q(Θ)(q_,q¯) such that eq. (16) holds and a symmetric equilibrium exists.

To prove uniqueness, we show sufficient conditions for χ(q)<0, q(q_,q¯). Using eq. (16), we have the following (omitting q as an argument)

(17)χ(q)=(BS+BS)(BSBS)BS(BS+BSBSBS)(BSBS)2=SS(B2BB)+BB(S2SS)(BSBS)2.

Thus we have that, q(q_,q¯), B(q)<0, S(q)>0, B(q)<0, and S(q)>0, if c(q)0 or c(q)<0 not too negative by assumption. For χ(q) to be monotonically decreasing in q over (q_,q¯) , we need to satisfy S2SS>0. This condition holds if

cqc<ηs(q)1,

where ηs(q)=S(q)q/S(q)>1, due to the convexity of S(q). Hence, we also need c(q)0, not too large. Therefore, as long as c(q)0 not too positive and c(q)<0 not too negative to preserve the properties of B(q) and S(q), we have χ(q)<0, q(q_,q¯). As a result, there exists a unique equilibrium q(q_,q¯), Θ(0,).

Notice that we cannot have an equilibrium with q(0,q_). Since B(q_)=u(q_)c(q_)c(q_)q_=0, we have u(q_)>c(q_), q_<qe, where u(qe)=c(qe), and B(q)>0 over (0,q_). In any competitive search equilibrium, if q(0,q_), a positive measure of sellers can deviate and increase q, and increase buyers’ surplus B(q) while sellers’ surplus S(q) also increases.

On the other hand, for any competitive search equilibrium with q(q¯,q^], where u(q^)=c(q^), B(q)<0 over this interval and S(q)=0, since the implied queue length Θ=0. A positive measure of sellers can deviate and post q1=q¯ϵ, attracting a positive measure of buyers by offering them B(q1)>0, and get positive surplus S(q1)>0. Hence, we cannot have q(q¯,q^] in any competitive search equilibrium.

We are then left to show that for any Θ(0,), neither q_ nor q¯ is an equilibrium. Consider the Lagrangian of the competitive search problem:

maxq,θα(θ)S(q)+λ[α(θ)θB(q)U¯],

which yields the following necessary (and sufficient) conditions

Lq=α(θ)S(q)+λα(θ)θB(q)=0,Lθ=α(θ)S(q)+λ[α(θ)θα(θ)θ2]B(q)=0.

These conditions lead to eq. (16) and are valid for any θ=Θ(0,). Now transform the second condition as

λθ=ε(θ)1ε(θ)S(q)B(q),

with ε(θ)=α(θ)θα(θ). Substituting into the first condition, we have that

Lq=α(θ)S(q)+ε(θ)1ε(θ)S(q)B(q)α(θ)B(q).

Since B(q_)=0,

Lq|q=q_=α(θ)S(q_)>0,

and B(q¯)=0 implies

Lq|q=q¯=<0.

Therefore, neither q_ nor q¯ is an equilibrium for θ=Θ(0,).

Finally, recall that ε(Θ)<0 , which holds for a large set of matching technologies. From eq. (16), we have that

ε(Θ)dΘ=χ(q)dqdqdΘ>0dpdΘ=c(q)dqdΘ>0.

Therefore, any increase in Θ leads to higher q and p over (q_,q¯).

C Proof of Proposition 2

Recall that for sellers, the free entry condition is given by

α(Θ)[c(q(Θ))q(Θ)c(q(Θ))]=k.

It is easy to show that the left-hand side of the previous equation is strictly increasing in Θ(0,) for q(Θ)(q_,q¯). Only for a very specific value of the entry cost, kc, we have that q(Θc)=qe. In this case, entry is efficient. However, entry is inefficiently low whenever k>kcΘ>Θc and q(Θ)>qe, or excessively high when k<kcΘ<Θc and q(Θ)<qe . When sellers face low entry costs, the equilibrium prescribes larger surpluses for buyers. In contrast, for very large entry costs, sellers are able to extract almost all of the surplus of the match. A low entry cost facilitates entry and tilts the bargaining power afforded by the market (via Θ) towards buyers. The reverse is observed when sellers face large entry costs.

D Proof of Lemma 2

Define q¯ such that c(q¯)=q¯u(q¯), i.e., S(q¯)=0, and p¯=u(q¯). We summarize the buyer’s optimal ex-post choice as follows:

p={c(q~)/q~forp(0,p¯),u(q~)forp(p¯,).

It is important to highlight that both of these solutions imply a monotone relationship between quantity and price. Notice the following

p<p¯q~(p)=q~2q~c(q~)c(q~)>0 (binding),p>p¯q~(p)=1/u(q~)<0 (not binding).

In a competitive search equilibrium with Θ(0,) , the positive measure of deviating sellers can choose a price that is either in [p¯,) and the constraint is not binding, or in (0,p¯) under binding constraint. Define the first possible deviation as p1=u(q~1) and the second possible deviation as p2=c(q~2)/q~2. It is easy to show that the buyers’ expected payoffs are

U1α(Θ)Θ[u(q~1)q~1u(q~1)] and α(Θ)Θ[u(q~2)q~2c(q~2)/q~2]U2,

while for sellers we have

π1α(Θ)[q~1u(q~1)c(q~1)]>0=π2α(Θ)[q~2c(q~2)/q~2c(q~2)].

It is clear that π2=0 holds when sellers receive no surplus. Thus no sellers would deviate and offer p2 and q~2 in a submarket. Sellers fully anticipate that the best ex-post choice of buyers is to fully extract all of their surplus. It must be then that the competitive search equilibrium price is p[p¯,). The optimal ex-post choice is then p1=u(q~1)[p¯,). In other words, sellers anticipate that q~1(p1) is the equilibrium buyers’ best response.

E Proof of Proposition 3

The proof is very similar to the one of Proposition 1. First, to show existence, we use again the fact that

(18)ε(Θ)=B(q)S(q)B(q)S(q)B(q)S(q)χ(q),

where under p=u(q), S(q)=u(q)qc(q) and B(q)=u(q)u(q)q. !q_>0 such that S(q_)=0, which implies u(q_)c(q_)=u(q_)q_>0q_<qe (the efficient quantity). Also !q¯>0 such that S(q¯)=0. For q(q_,q¯), we find (omitting q as an argument) the following

S=uq+uc<0,S=2uc+uq<0 if u0 or u>0 not too large.

Thus, under these sufficient conditions we have that S(q) is downward concave. For buyers,

B=uq>0B=uuq>0 if u0 or u>0 not too large.

Hence, under these sufficient conditions we have that B(q) is upward convex. We also have that χ(q_)=0 and χ(q¯)=1, with χ(q)>0, q(q_,q¯). Again, since ε(Θ)(0,1), Θ(0,), there exists a q(q_,q¯) satisfying eq. (18).

To prove uniqueness, we need χ(q)>0, q(q_,q¯). Using eq. (18) and the properties of B(q) and S(q), we can derive the following sufficient condition

uqu<ηb(q)1(B2BB)>0, 

where ηb(q)=B(q)q/B(q)>1, due to the convexity of B(q). Note that if u is negative while preserving the properties of B(q) and S(q) as above, or u0 but not too positive, this condition holds and we have χ(q)>0, q(q_,q¯). Then, there exists a unique equilibrium q(q_,q¯), Θ(0,).

Notice that we cannot have an equilibrium with q(0,q_). Since S(q_)=u(q_)c(q_)+u(q_)q_=0, we have u(q_)>c(q_) and q_<qe where u(qe)=c(qe), and S(q)>0 over this interval. In any competitive search equilibrium, if q(0,q_), a positive measure of buyers can increase q, and increase sellers’ surplus S(q) while buyers’ surplus B(q) also increases.

On the other hand, for any competitive search equilibrium with q(q¯,q^], where u(q^)=c(q^), S(q)<0 over this interval and B(q)=0, since sellers will not produce for negative surplus. A positive measure of sellers can deviate and post q1=q¯ϵ, attracting a positive measure of buyers by offering them B(q1)>0, and get positive surplus S(q1)>0. Hence, we cannot have q(q¯,q^] in any competitive search equilibrium.

We are left to show that for any Θ(0,), neither q_ nor q¯ is an equilibrium. Consider the Lagrangian of the competitive search problem:

maxq,θα(θ)S(q)+λ[α(θ)θB(q)U¯],

which yields the following necessary (and sufficient) conditions

Lq=α(θ)S(q)+λα(θ)θB(q)=0,Lθ=α(θ)S(q)+λ[α(θ)θα(θ)θ2]B(q)=0.

These conditions lead to eq. (18) and are valid for any θ=Θ(0,). As in the proof of Proposition 1, we can derive

Lq=α(θ)S(q)+ε(θ)1ε(θ)S(q)B(q)α(θ)B(q).

Since S(q_)=0,

Lq|q=q_=ε(θ)1ε(θ)S(q_)B(q_)α(θ)B(q_)>0,

and S(q¯)=0 implies

Lq|q=q¯=α(θ)S(q¯)<0.

Therefore, neither q_ nor q¯ is an equilibrium when θ=Θ(0,).

Finally, by assumption we have ε(Θ)<0. From eq. (18)

ε(Θ)dΘ=χ(q)dqdqdΘ<0dpdΘ=u(q)dqdΘ>0.

Therefore, any increase in Θ leads to lower q and higher p over(q_,q¯).

F Proof of Proposition 4

The free entry condition faced by a seller is given by

α(Θ)[u(q(Θ))q(Θ)c(q(Θ))]=k.

It is easy to show that the left-hand side of the previous condition is strictly increasing in Θ(0,) for q(Θ)(q_,q¯). Note that entry is efficient only for a very particular value of kc, which implies a specific market tightness, Θc, such that q(Θc)=qe. Otherwise, entry is inefficient. For k>kc, we have Θ>Θc and q(Θ)<qe, while for k<kc we have that q(Θ)>qe. For low cost of entry, the equilibrium is such that sellers’ surplus is small (buyers large), while for very large entry cost, sellers obtain large surpluses (buyers small). These findings echo the entry results under marginal cost pricing of the previous section. However, there are some important differences. First, in equilibrium now we have q(p)<0 with marginal utility pricing. Moreover, the direction of inefficiency is reversed when compared to marginal cost pricing. Therefore, we can conclude that for efficiency properties, it matters if quantity is chosen ex-post by sellers or by buyers.

G Proof of Proposition 5

The proof follows from the text.

Acknowledgements:

We would like to thank the editor as well as the referees for their helpful comments and suggestions, and seminar participants at the University of Hawaii Manoa. Julien and Wang acknowledge financial support from the ARC grant DP1701014229. The usual disclaimers apply.

References

Acemoglu, D., and R. Shimer. 1999. “Efficient Unemployment Insurance.” Journal of Political Economy 107: 893–928.10.1086/250084Search in Google Scholar

Albrecht, J., P. Gautier, and S. Vroman. 2014. “Efficient Entry in Competing Auctions.” American Economic Review 104: 3288–3296.10.1257/aer.104.10.3288Search in Google Scholar

Albrecht, J., P. Gautier, and S. Vroman. 2016. “Directed Search in the Housing Market.” Review of Economic Dynamics 19: 218–231.10.1016/j.red.2015.05.002Search in Google Scholar

Burdett, K., S. Shi, and R. Wright. 2001. “Pricing and Matching with Frictions.” Journal of Political Economy 109: 1060–1085.10.1086/322835Search in Google Scholar

Cai, X., P. Gautier, and R. Wolthoff. 2017. “Search Frictions, Competing Mechanisms and Optimal Market Segmentation.” Journal of Economic Theory 169: 453–473.10.1016/j.jet.2017.03.002Search in Google Scholar

Camera, G., and C. Selcuk. 2009. “Price Dispersion with Directed Search.” Journal of the European Economic Association 7 (6): 1193–1224.10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.6.1193Search in Google Scholar

Diamond, P. 1971. “A Model of Price Adjustment.” Journal of Economic Theory 3: 156–168.10.1016/0022-0531(71)90013-5Search in Google Scholar

Doyle, M., and J. Wong. 2013. “Wage Posting Without Full Commitment.” Review of Economic Dynamics 16: 231–252.10.1016/j.red.2012.12.002Search in Google Scholar

Faig, M., and B Jerez. 2005. “A Theory of Commerce.” Journal of Economic Theory 122: 60–99.10.1016/j.jet.2004.04.002Search in Google Scholar

Geromichalos, A. 2012. “Directed Search and Optimal Production.” Journal of Economic Theory 147: 2303–2331.10.1016/j.jet.2012.09.008Search in Google Scholar

Geromichalos, A. 2014. “Directed Search and the Bertrand Paradox.” International Economic Review 55: 1043–1065.10.1111/iere.12082Search in Google Scholar

Godenhielm, M., and K. Kultti. 2014. “Capacity Choice in a Large Market.” PLoS ONE 9: 1–7.10.1371/journal.pone.0101766Search in Google Scholar

Godenhielm, M., and K. Kultti. 2015. “Directed Search with Endogenous Capacity.” The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics 15: 211–249.10.1515/bejte-2014-0006Search in Google Scholar

Gomis-Porqueras, P., B. Julien, and C. Wang. 2017. “Strategic Advertising and Directed Search.” International Economic Review forthcoming.10.1111/iere.12235Search in Google Scholar

Hawkins, W. 2013. “Competitive Search, Efficiency, and Multi-worker Firms.” International Economic Review 54: 219–251.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2012.00731.xSearch in Google Scholar

Hosios, A. J. 1990. “On the Efficiency of Matching and Related Models of Search and Unemployment.” Review of Economic Studies 57: 279–298.10.2307/2297382Search in Google Scholar

Julien, B., J. Kennes, and I. King. 2000. “Bidding for Labor.” Review of Economic Dynamics 3: 619–649.10.1006/redy.1999.0089Search in Google Scholar

Kim, K., and P. Kircher. 2015. “Efficient Competition through Cheap Talk: The Case of Competing Auctions.” Econometrica 83: 1849–1875.10.3982/ECTA12103Search in Google Scholar

Lagos, R., G. Rocheteau, and R. Wright. 2017. “Liquidity: A New Monetarist Perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature 55 (2): 371–440.10.1257/jel.20141195Search in Google Scholar

Lester, B. 2010. “Directed Search with Multi-vacancy Firms.” Journal of Economic Theory 145: 2108–2132.10.1016/j.jet.2010.07.002Search in Google Scholar

Lester, B., L. Visschers, and R. Wolthoff. 2015. “Meeting Technologies and Optimal Trading Mechanisms in Competitive Search Markets.” Journal of Economic Theory 155: 1–15.10.1016/j.jet.2014.11.001Search in Google Scholar

Lester, B., L. Visschers, and R. Wolthoff. 2017. “Competing with Asking Prices.” Theoretical Economics 12: 731–770.10.3982/TE1846Search in Google Scholar

McAfee, R. 1993. “Mechanism Design by Competing Sellers.” Econometrica 61: 1281–1312.10.2307/2951643Search in Google Scholar

Moen, E. 1997. “Competitive Search Equilibrium.” Journal of Political Economy 105: 385–411.10.1086/262077Search in Google Scholar

Montgomery, J. D. 1991. “Social Networks and Labor-Market Outcomes: Toward an Economic Analysis.” American Economic Review 81: 1408–1418.Search in Google Scholar

Mortensen, D., and R. Wright. 2002. “Competitive Pricing and Efficiency in Search Equilibrium.” International Economic Review 43: 1–20.10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00001Search in Google Scholar

Nosal, E., and G. Rocheteau. 2011 Money, Payments and LiquidityCambridge, MA: MIT Press.10.7551/mitpress/9780262016285.001.0001Search in Google Scholar

Peters, M. 1984. “Bertrand Equilibrium with Capacity Constraints and Restricted Mobility.” Econometrica 52: 1117–1127.10.2307/1910990Search in Google Scholar

Peters, M. 2000. “Limits of Exact Equilibria for Capacity Constrained Sellers with Costly Search.” Journal of Economic Theory 95: 139–168.10.1006/jeth.2000.2667Search in Google Scholar

Peters, M., and S. Severinov. 1997. “Competition among Sellers Who Offer Auctions Instead of Prices.” Journal of Economic Theory 75: 141–179.10.1006/jeth.1997.2278Search in Google Scholar

Pissarides, C. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Rocheteau, G., and R. Wright. 2005. “Money in Search Equilibrium, in Competitive Equilibrium, and in Competitive Search Equilibrium.” Econometrica 73: 175–202.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00568.xSearch in Google Scholar

Rogerson, R., R. Shimer, and R. Wright. 2005. “Search-Theoretic Models of the Labor Market: A Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 43: 959–988.10.1257/002205105775362014Search in Google Scholar

Shimer, R. 1996. Contracts in Frictional Labor Markets, mimeo.Search in Google Scholar

Published Online: 2017-9-13

© 2017 Walter de Gruyter GmbH, Berlin/Boston

Downloaded on 26.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.1515/bejte-2016-0083/html
Scroll to top button