Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The impact of ‘central places’ on spatial spending patterns: evidence from Flemish local government cultural expenditures

  • Original Article
  • Published:
Journal of Cultural Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Governments often see it as their responsibility to support cultural life and at times spend a significant amount of resources in the pursuit of this goal. The present article analyses whether and how municipalities influence each other in this decision to spend resources on the arts (using data on local government cultural spending in 304 Flemish municipalities in 2002). Following ‘central place theory’, the focal point of the analysis is the idea that––especially for cultural expenditures––large municipalities (and, specifically, ‘central places’) may affect their neighbours’ behaviour differently than small municipalities. The empirical analysis supports this idea. Indeed, we show that Flemish municipalities’ cultural spending is generally positively affected by that in neighbouring municipalities. This pattern is, however, significantly more complex for municipalities neighbouring the 13 largest Flemish cities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Withers (1979) and Jenkins and Austen-Smith (1987) study the relationships between public cultural spending by different levels of government (arguing that, say, federal arts outlays in a given jurisdiction affect state and local expenditures in that same jurisdiction). We focus on horizontal rather than vertical interdependencies between governments.

  2. The most straightforward definition of a jurisdiction’s neighbourhood is geographical (e.g. jurisdictions sharing a border). Still, one might also define the ‘peer’ group in terms of socio-economic or political similarities across jurisdictions (see e.g. Baicker 2005; Van Parys and Verbeke 2007).

  3. The reason––taken from financial economics––is that a decrease in the ‘strike price’ of an option (e.g. through lower anticipated travel costs) to acquire a given underlying commodity (i.e. cultural activities) increases its value.

  4. The influx of consumers from other jurisdictions may lead to (or enhance) potential congestion problems. As this generates costs for consumers (such as longer lines to buy tickets or reduced consumption experience due to noise; cfr. Traub and Missong 2005), this is likely to strengthen the point made here: viz. pressure on governments in all concerned municipalities to increase cultural goods provision.

  5. Empirical evidence on the electoral cost of taxation mostly confirms the idea that voters engage in such relative performance assessments (e.g. Besley and Case 1995; Ågren 2005; Vermeir and Heyndels 2006; Bosch and Solé-Ollé 2007; see, however, Revelli 2002).

  6. This ‘option value’ of the arts has received considerable attention in the literature. Individuals, so the argument goes, might be prepared to pay “for the option to consume art at some unspecified future time, fully realizing that they may never choose to exercise that option” (Shanahan and Hendon 1979, p. 12; for empirical support see Throsby and Withers 1986; Morrison and West 1986; Bille Hansen 1997).

  7. Beside these specific grants and general-purpose grants, higher-level governments may also provide matching grants when municipalities organize cultural activities. Unfortunately, we lack data on the prevalence and importance of such matching grants.

  8. Data availability precludes inclusion of the remaining four municipalities. Note also that the 2002 data are the most recent figures available and that a change in the municipal accounting rules in 2000 prevents us from using comparable data for a longer period of time. This effectively constrains us to a cross-section analysis. One important drawback of this is that there is no temporal development, making it hard to speak of ‘reactions’ to other municipalities’ behaviour in our findings. Essentially, we assess the ‘equilibrium’ outcome of the interdependent process at a given point in time.

  9. The Flemish municipalities spent €132.6 million on local public libraries in 2002. The ‘strict’ definition, however, excludes this spending. The reason is that Flemish Regional legislation requires every municipality to have its own library. One could argue that this diverts cultural spending from the budget of the higher-level government to that of the Flemish municipalities and thus ‘biases’ local spending upwards. Nonetheless, re-estimating the model including library expenditures and subsidies (the latter amounted to €43 million in 2002) does not alter the inferences from the analysis (full results available upon request).

  10. We assume that spending decisions are commonly observable and employ the contemporaneous level of cultural spending in the neighbouring jurisdictions. This assumption––also made in Buettner (2001) and Allers and Elhorst (2005)––is plausible since council meetings in Flanders are open to the public (except when personnel issues are discussed).

  11. Given the small average distance between Flemish municipalities, we also experimented with a possible effect from second order neighbours (i.e. neighbours of neighbours; Heyndels and Vuchelen 1998). As such effects were never detected, this is not retained in the final version of the article. One might also use a distance-decaying weights matrix (with weights equal to the inverse of the distance between municipalities) to construct the neighbourhood variable. We return to the results of such a specification in footnote 21 (and are grateful to Stefan Van Parys for providing these data).

  12. This redefinition is also important to appropriately account for ‘space’ in the spatial econometrics model. In fact, Mutl (2006) has shown that size adjusted weighting matrices are crucial in settings with widely heterogeneous jurisdictions.

  13. This is the case for 13 Flemish cities: Aalst, Antwerpen, Brugge, Genk, Gent, Hasselt, Kortrijk, Leuven, Mechelen, Oostende, Roeselare, Sint-Niklaas and Turnhout (see Moesen 2001). Note that these 13 cities are also the only ones designated as either ‘large’ or ‘regional’ cities through an extensive cluster-analysis incorporating dozens of socio-economic indicators in five categories (i.e. use of land and buildings, income levels, economic activity and structure of working population, demographic structure and externalities) by Dessoy (1998).

  14. Since there are only 13 central places identified, assessing H2b is empirically difficult due to a lack of observations. Nonetheless, preliminary tests indicate that the reaction of central places to their (smaller) neighbours is always positive (though not necessarily statistically significant). This indicates absence of free riding behaviour, as expected under H2b. Nonetheless, it also suggests some interaction between central places and their neighbours (due to yardstick competition, reference point effects or acquired taste effects, cfr. H4). Note that we also tested for the reaction of central places to the cultural spending in other central places (rather than their immediate geographical neighbours). Though coefficient estimations are positive, as might be expected, they fail to reach statistical significance. Given the insignificance of these results, we have not retained this extension in the main analysis.

  15. One alternative means to test H3 is to interact NonCP-neighbours spending with a dummy variable equal to 1 for neighbours of central places (0 otherwise). This implies estimation of regression Eq. 1 with the following neighbourhood variables: ψ (CP-neighbours spending) + ζ (NonCP-neighbours spending) + ξ (NonCP-neighbours spending)*NoCP, where CP- and NonCP-neighbours spending are constructed as before, ξ, ζ and ψ are parameters to be estimated and NoCP (Neighbour of Central Place) is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the municipality shares a border with one of the 13 Flemish central places. H3 leads us to expect a negative effect on the interaction term (ξ), indicating that the behaviour of small neighbours is less influential on the behaviour of municipalities adjoining a central place than on those not bordering a central place. While this approach effectively introduces multiple spatial regimes into the model (cfr. Bordignon et al. 2003; Allers and Elhorst 2005), this alternative modelling strategy (inappropriately) treats municipalities that do not share a border with a central place as if they have a central place neighbour with no cultural spending. This is not the case using the approach in the main text. The results under both approaches are, however, qualitatively similar (see footnote 22).

  16. An anonymous referee pointed out that this variable may well be endogenous. However, the standard Hausman test of exogeneity does not support this and treating the variable as endogenous does not affect our results (available upon request).

  17. The data concerning a party’s ideological position were obtained from Rihoux (2001) and are based on a self-placement survey asking presidents and spokesmen of the parties in the municipalities to locate their party on an ideological scale between 0 (Left) and 10 (Right). The figures range from 2.6 (Agalev) to 6.0 (VLD) (the extreme-right-wing party Vlaams Blok––now Vlaams Belang––was not represented in any local government and is therefore not in the dataset).

  18. Preliminary tests show, however, that the basic findings of the analyses shown in columns (1) through (3) are also retrieved using ML estimation (even when we control for spatial error dependence). In fact, the coefficient estimates (as well as statistical significance) are very similar under both procedures. The results in Columns (4) and (6) would necessitate giving some municipalities in the sample values from two spatial weights matrices (which we were, unfortunately, unable to adequately implement using Matlab).

  19. In the analyses where central places are awarded a special status (reported in columns (4) through (6)), we expand the set of instruments with dummy variables indicating whether or not a given municipality borders one of more central places. This is necessary to increase the strength of the instruments in these estimations (though their exclusion does not affect the estimation results).

  20. In order to ensure that we are actually measuring spatial interdependence, we re-estimated the model using a weights matrix where neighbours are defined according to the alphabetical order of municipalities’ names (cfr. Case et al. 1993; Brown and Rork 2005; Geys 2006). Every municipality is awarded one ‘neighbour’ preceding and following it in the alphabetical ordering. Since this alphabetical ranking has nothing to do with the competitive forces between municipalities, the use of such a weighing scheme should not lead to significant estimates of the spatial parameter. In line with this prediction, the estimations indicate the absence of spatial interactions using these alphabetical ‘neighbours’ (results available upon request).

  21. Using a distance-decay weights matrix gives a relatively large weight to cultural expenditures of large cities in the neighbourhood variable of all municipalities (due to the sheer size of cultural spending by large cities). Free riding behaviour on large city cultural spending (cfr. H2a) should then lead to more negative (or lower positive) values of the neighbourhood parameter estimate when using a distance-decay weights matrix. Effectively, we even observe a negative spatial interaction coefficient (available upon request). This indicates that using a distance-based weights matrix (which implicitly gives higher weights to cities), the free riding effect dominates.

  22. The alternative proposed in footnote 15––i.e. inclusion of an interaction between NonCP-neighbours spending (i.e. the population-weighted average level of cultural spending in those of a municipality’s neighbours that are not central places) and a dummy variable equal to 1 for neighbours of central places (0 otherwise)––indicates that the interaction term has the expected negative sign, but is statistically insignificant at conventional levels. Hence, being situated next to a central place leads to a weaker reaction to small neighbours’ spending (though insignificantly so). Note also that including a dummy variable for neighbours of central places directly into the analysis––in order to check whether vicinity to a central place an sich affects policy decisions––gives insignificant results (such that this dummy is not retained in the final model; except in the instrument vector).

  23. The Brussels Capital Region is geographically surrounded by Flanders. Flemish municipalities bordering Brussels may thus be affected by cultural spending decisions in the Brussels Capital Region. Unfortunately, lack of data on cultural spending in the Brussels municipalities prevents a direct test of this possibility. As an indirect test, we re-estimated the model excluding municipalities that neighbour the Brussels Capital Region. The findings are quantitatively similar to those presented in the main text (available upon request). Also, including a dummy variable to assess whether neighbours of Brussels act significantly different from the remaining Flemish municipalities indicates that this is not the case.

References

  • Ågren, H. (2005). Essays on political representation, electoral accountability and strategic interactions. (Doctoral Dissertation, Uppsala: Uppsala University).

  • Allers, M. A., & Elhorst, J. P. (2005). Tax mimicking and yardstick competition among local governments in the Netherlands. International Tax and Public Finance, 12(4), 493–513.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anselin, L., Bera, A. K., Florax, R., & Yoon, M. J. (1996). Simple diagnostic tests for spatial dependence. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 26, 77–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., & Heyndels, B. (2000). Reference point effects in local taxation: It all depends on how you look at it. National Tax Association Papers and Proceedings, 335–341.

  • Ashworth, J., Geys, B., & Heyndels, B. (2005). Government weakness and local public debt development in Flemish municipalities. International Tax and Public Finance, 12(4), 395–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, J., Geys, B., & Heyndels, B. (2006). Determinants of tax innovation: The case of environmental taxes in Flemish municipalities. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 223–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baicker, K. (2005). The spillover effects of state spending. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 529–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Murphy, K. M. (1988). A theory of rational addiction. Journal of Political Economy, 96(4), 675–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Case, A. (1995). Incumbent behavior: Vote seeking, tax setting and yardstick competition. American Economic Review, 85(1), 25–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bille Hansen, T. (1997). The willingness-to-pay for the Royal Theatre in Copenhagen as a public good. Journal of Cultural Economics, 21, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1948). On the rationale of group decision-making. Journal of Political Economy, 56, 133–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau, J. R., & Hall, R. H. (1986). The supply of performing arts in metropolitian areas. Urban Affairs Quarterly, 22(1), 42–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordignon, M., Cerniglia, F., & Revelli, F. (2003). In search of yardstick competition: a spatial analysis of Italian municipality property tax setting. Journal of Urban Economics, 54(2), 199–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosch, N., & Solé-Ollé, A. (2007), Yardstick competition and the political costs of raising taxes: An empirical analysis of Spanish municipalities. International Tax and Public Finance, 14(1), 71–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boter, J., Rouwendal, J., & Wedel, M. (2005). Employing travel time to compare the value of competing cultural organizations. Journal of Cultural Economics, 29(1), 19–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradford, D., & Oates, W. E. (1971). Toward a predictive theory of intergovernmental grants. American Economic Review, 61, 440–448.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1977). Towards a tax constitution for Leviathan. Journal of Public Economics, 8, 255–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, A. C. (2001). Who opposes government arts funding? Public Choice, 108, 355–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, R. P., & Rork, J. C. (2005). Copycat gaming: A spatial analysis of state lottery structure. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35, 795–807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner, J. (2003). Strategic interaction among governments: An overview of empirical studies. International Regional Science Review, 26(2), 175–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buettner, T. (2001). Local business taxation and competition for capital: The choice of the tax rate. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 31(2–3), 215–245.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, A. C., Rosen, H. S., & Hines, J. R. (1993). Budget spillovers and fiscal policy interdependence: Evidence from the States. Journal of Public Economics, 52, 285–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coffé, H. (2006). The vulnerable institutional complexity: The 2004 regional elections in Brussels. Regional and Federal Studies, 16(1), 99–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cragg, J. G., & Donald, S. G. (1993). Testing identifiability and specification in instrumental variable models. Econometric Theory, 9, 222–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig, S. G., & Inman, R. P. (1986). Education, welfare and ‘a new federalism’: State budgeting in a federalist public economy. In: H. S. Rosen (eds.), Studies in state and local public finance (pp. 187–222). Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Das, D., Kelejian, H. H., & Prucha, I. R. (2003). Finite sample properties of estimators of spatial autoregressive models with autoregressive disturbances. Papers in Regional Science, 82, 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Graaff, T., Boter, J., & Rouwendal J. (2007). On spatial differences in attractiveness of Dutch museums. Free University Amsterdam, mimeo.

  • Dessoy, A. (1998). Sociaal-economische typologie van de gemeenten. Tijdschrift van het Gemeentekrediet, 205(3), 17–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (2005). What values should count in the arts? The tension between economic effects and cultural value. Institute for empirical research in economics working paper, No 253, University of Zurich.

  • Getzner, M. (2002). Determinants of public cultural expenditures: An exploratory time series analysis for Austria. Journal of Cultural Economics, 26, 287–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Getzner, M. (2004). Exploring voter preferences in cultural policy: A case study for Austria. Empirica, 31, 27–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B. (2006). Looking across borders: A test of spatial policy interdependence using local government efficiency ratings. Journal of Urban Economics, 60(3), 443–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B. (2007). Government weakness and local public debt cycles: Evidence from Flemish municipalities. Local Government Studies, 33(2), 239–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geys, B., & Vermeir J. (2007). Taxation and presidential approval: Separate effects from tax burden and tax structure turbulence? WZB Berlin, mimeo.

  • Goeminne, S., Geys, B., & Smolders, C. (2007). Political fragmentation and projected tax revenues: Evidence from Flemish municipalities. International Tax and Public Finance, (forthcoming).

  • Greene, W. H. (1993). Econometric analysis. 3rd ed. Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heilbrun, J. (1992). Art and culture as central place functions. Urban Studies, 29(2), 205–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyndels, B. (2001). Asymmetries in the flypaper effect: Empirical evidence for the flemish municipalities. Applied Economics, 33, 1329–1334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heyndels, B., & Vuchelen, J. (1998). Tax mimicking in Belgian municipalities. National Tax Journal, 51, 89–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macro-economic policy. American Political Science Review, 71, 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). The flypaper effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 217–226.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofferbert, R. I., & Urice, J. K. (1985). Small-scale policy: The federal stimulus versus competing explanations for state funding of the arts. American Journal of Political Science, 29, 308–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins, S., & Austen-Smith, D. (1987). Interdependent decision-making in non-profit industries: A simultaneous equation analysis of English provincial theatre. International Journal of Industrial Organisation, 5, 149–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian, H., & Robinson, D. (1993). A suggested method of estimation for spatial interdependent models with autocorrelated errors and an application to a country expenditure model. Papers in Regional Science, 72(3), 297–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian, H., & Prucha, I. (1998). A generalised spatial two-stage least squares procedure for estimating a spatial autoregressive model with autoregressive disturbances. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 17(1), 99–121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krebs, S., & Pommerehne, W. W. (1995). Politico-economic interactions of German public performing arts institutions. Journal of Cultural Economics, 19(1), 17–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, J. (2006). Spatial interaction model of spillovers from locally provided public services. Regional Studies, 40(6), 631–644.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lévy-Garboua, L., & Montmarquette, C. (1996). A microeconometric study of theater demand. Journal of Cultural Economics, 20(1), 25–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manski, C. F. (1993). Identification of endogenous social effects: The reflection problem. Review of Economic Studies, 60, 531–542.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1891). Principles of economics. London: MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministerie van de Vlaamse Gemeenschap. (2002). VRIND: Vlaamse Regionale Indicatoren (Brussels: Administratie Planning en Statistiek, Ministerie van de Vlaamse Gemeenschap).

  • Ministerie van de Vlaamse Gemeenschap. (2003). VRIND: Vlaamse Regionale Indicatoren (Brussels: Administratie Planning en Statistiek, Ministerie van de Vlaamse Gemeenschap).

  • Moesen, W. (2001). Openbare financiering en de nieuwe steden. Leuven: Centrum voor Economische Studiën.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, W. G., & West, E. G. (1986). Subsidies for the performing arts: Evidence on voter preference. Journal of Behavioral Economics, 15, 57–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C., & Murrell, P. (1986). Interest groups and the size of government. Public Choice, 48, 125–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mutl, J. (2006). Misspecification of space: An illustration using growth convergence regressions. Paper presented at the international workshop on spatial econometrics and statistics, Rome (Italy), May 2006.

  • O’Hagan, J. (1996). Access to and participation in the arts: The case of those with low income/educational attainment. Journal of Cultural Economics, 20(4), 269–282.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollak, R. A. (1970). Habit formation and dynamic demand functions. Journal of Political Economy, 78(4), 745–763.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. W. (1982). Steuern, staatsausgaben und stimmbürgerverhalten: eine empirische untersuchung am beispiel der öffentlichen subventionierung des theaters. Jahrbucher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 197(5), 437–462.

    Google Scholar 

  • Redoano, M. (2007). Fiscal interactions among European countries: Does the EU matter? CSGR working paper series, No. 222/07.

  • Revelli, F. (2002). Local taxes, national politics and spatial interactions in English district election results. European Journal of Political Economy, 18, 281–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli, F. (2005). On spatial public finance empirics. International Tax and Public Finance, 12(4), 475–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rihoux, B. (2001). Iedereen naar het politieke centrum en voorstander van de Nieuwe Politieke Cultuur?: de ideologische positionering van de lokale partijafdelingen in België. Tijdschrift van Dexia Bank, 216, 7–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salmon, P. G. (1987). Decentralization as an incentive scheme. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 3(2), 24–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, G. G., & Rose, A. (1998). Public orchestra funding in Germany: An empirical investigation. Journal of Cultural Economics, 22, 227–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schulze, G. G., & Ursprung, H. W. (2000). La Donna e mobile––or is she? Voter preferences and public support for the performing arts. Public Choice, 102, 129–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seaman, B. A. (2005). Attendance and public participation in the performing arts: A review of the empirical literature. Working paper 06–25, Georgia State University.

  • Shanahan, J., & Hendon, W. (1979). Symposium on subsidization of cultural activities. Journal of Behavioral Economics, 8(1), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer, A. (1985). A theory of yardstick competition. RAND Journal of Economics, 16(3), 319–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soetevent, A. R. (2006). Empirics of the identification of social interactions: An evaluation of the approaches and their results. Journal of Economic Surveys, 20, 193–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A. (2003). Electoral accountability and tax mimicking: The effects of electoral margins, coalition government and ideology. European Journal of Political Economy, 19, 685–713.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A. (2006). Expenditure spillovers and fiscal interactions: Empirical evidence from local governments in Spain. Journal of Urban Economics, 59(1), 32–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tavares, J. (2004). Does right or left matter? Cabinets, credibility and fiscal adjustments. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2447–2468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4, 199–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, C. D. (1994). The production and consumption of the arts: A view of cultural economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Throsby, C. D., & Withers, G. A. (1986). Strategic bias and demand for public goods: Theory and an application to the arts. Journal of Public Economics, 31, 307–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Traub, S. (2005). Quality investment and price formation in the performing arts sector: A spatial analysis, University of Kiel. (Unpublished manuscript).

  • Traub, S., & Missong, M. (2005). On the public provision of the performing arts. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 35(6), 862–882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Parys, S., & verbeke, T. (2007). Tax competition among Belgian municipalities: A multi-dimensional battle? paper presented at the first world spatial econometrics association meeting, Cambridge (UK), July 2007.

  • Verhoeff, R. (1992). Explaining differences in the geographical reach of performances. Journal of Cultural Economics, 16(2), 73–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vermeir, J., & Heyndels, B. (2006). Tax policy and yardstick voting in Flemish municipal elections. Applied Economics, 38(19), 2285–2298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Withers, G. (1979). Private demand for public subsidies: An econometric study of cultural support in Australia. Journal of Cultural Economics, 3(1), 53–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to Erik Desmedt, Stefaan Swaels and Stefan Van Parys for providing data and to Jan Brueckner, Hilde Coffé, Michiel Evers, Marc Jegers, James LeSage, Jan Mutl, Robert Nuscheler, Federico Revelli, three anonymous referees and participants of the 14th ACEI Conference on Cultural Economics (Vienna, July 2006), 2nd IEB Workshop on Fiscal Federalism (Seville, June 2007), 1st World Spatial Econometrics Meeting (Cambridge, July 2007) and research seminars at ZEW and KULeuven for helpful comments. The usual caveat applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Benny Geys.

Additional information

K. Werck, B. Heyndels and B. Geys contributed equally to this article and are given in reverse alphabetical order.

Appendix A: Summary statistics

Appendix A: Summary statistics

Table A1 Summary statistics (N = 304)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Werck, K., Heyndels, B. & Geys, B. The impact of ‘central places’ on spatial spending patterns: evidence from Flemish local government cultural expenditures. J Cult Econ 32, 35–58 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-007-9056-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10824-007-9056-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation